C greatness

magnitude of tax incidence

Tax Incidence
The economic effects, and therefore the equity, of many taxes cannot be fully understood because of the difficulty in determining where their burdens really fall. Even the individual income tax, which is presumed to fall entirely on the legal taxpayer, has indirect consequences in the economy; it influences decisions to work, save, and invest, and these decisions affect other people. Perhaps the most difficult tax burdens to pin down are those of the corporate-profits tax. Depending on the structure and flexibility of the market within which a corporation competes, the tax may in some cases simply lower corporate profits and dividends; in other cases, it may broadly reduce the incomes of all owners of property and businesses. To the extent that corporations compensate for the tax by raising the prices of their products, the incidence of the tax may be said to be shifted forward to consumers. To the extent that tax-reduced corporate profit margins hold down wages, the incidence of the tax is shifted backward to workers. 

Similar disagreements arise over the incidence of local property taxes and over the employers' share of social security payroll taxes. Even the long-established view that retail sales taxes are shifted forward from retailers to consumers is challenged in a world in which wages and government transfers (that is, income payments such as social security) are indexed, or automatically adjusted upward, for inflation. Inclusion of the sales tax in the Consumer Price Index insulates recipients of indexed incomes against inflation-induced tax increases and therefore puts the burden of those increases on the recipients of nonindexed incomes. As awareness grows of the difficulties in pinning down the burden patterns of various taxes, the old distinction between direct (unshiftable) and indirect (shiftable) taxes becomes relatively meaningless. 

Other Effects of Taxation.
Despite the difficulties of precise measurement, governments are appropriately concerned with the vertical pattern of the tax burden: Does it fall proportionately more heavily on the rich than on the poor (progressive taxation)? Does it burden everyone to the same degree in relation to taxpaying ability (proportional taxation)? Or does it place a relatively heavier burden on the poor (regressive taxation)? In most modern nations, a generally progressive tax structure is considered desirable for two reasons. First, a progressive tax is considered more equitable (because the wealthy have more ability to pay). Second, extremes of wealth and poverty are considered injurious to the economic and social well-being of a society, and a progressive tax structure tends to moderate such extremes. 

On the other hand, tax rates that are too progressive-that rise too steeply-may discourage both work and investment by removing much of the reward. In the early 1980s concern about this problem in the U.S. and elsewhere attracted the attention of policymakers to so-called supply-side economics-to economic theories emphasizing the importance of ensuring that taxes do not drain away incentives to invest, either from individuals or from businesses. In 1986 the U.S. Congress instituted a major overhaul of the income tax system. G.F.B.